Where modern macroeconomics went wrong

7 Nov, 2020 at 09:19 | Posted in Economics | 8 Comments

DSGE models seem to take it as a religious tenet that consumption should be explained by a model of a representative agent maximizing his utility over an infinite lifetime without borrowing constraints. Doing so is called micro-founding the model. But economics is a behavioral science. If Keynes was right that individuals saved a constant fraction of their income, an aggregate model based on that assumption is micro-founded.FRANCE-US-ECONOMY-NOBEL-STIGLITZOf course, the economy consists of individuals who are different, but all of whom have a finite life and most of whom are credit constrained, and who do adjust their consumption behavior, if slowly, in response to changes in their economic environment. Thus, we also know that individuals do not save a constant fraction of their income, come what may. So both stories, the DSGE and the old-fashioned Keynesian, are simplifications. When they are incorporated into a simple macro-model, one is saying the economy acts as if… And then the question is, which provides a better description; a better set of prescriptions; and a better basis for future elaboration of the model. The answer is not obvious. The criticism of DSGE is thus not that it involves simplification: all models do. It is that it has made the wrong modelling choices, choosing complexity in areas where the core story of macroeconomic fluctuations could be told using simpler hypotheses, but simplifying in areas where much of the macroeconomic action takes place.

Joseph Stiglitz

Stiglitz is, of course, absolutely right.

DSGE models are worse than useless — and still, mainstream economists seem to be impressed by the ‘rigour’ brought to macroeconomics by New-Classical-New-Keynesian DSGE models and its rational expectations and microfoundations!

It is difficult to see why.

Take the rational expectations assumption. Rational expectations in the mainstream economists’ world imply that relevant distributions have to be time independent. This amounts to assuming that an economy is like a closed system with known stochastic probability distributions for all different events. In reality, it is straining one’s beliefs to try to represent economies as outcomes of stochastic processes. An existing economy is a single realization tout court, and hardly conceivable as one realization out of an ensemble of economy-worlds since an economy can hardly be conceived as being completely replicated over time. It is — to say the least — very difficult to see any similarity between these modelling assumptions and the expectations of real persons. In the world of the rational expectations hypothesis, we are never disappointed in any other way than as when we lose at the roulette wheels. But real life is not an urn or a roulette wheel. And that’s also the reason why allowing for cases where agents make ‘predictable errors’ in DSGE models doesn’t take us any closer to a relevant and realist depiction of actual economic decisions and behaviours. If we really want to have anything of interest to say on real economies, financial crisis and the decisions and choices real people make we have to replace the rational expectations hypothesis with more relevant and realistic assumptions concerning economic agents and their expectations than childish roulette and urn analogies.

Or take the consumption model built into the DSGE models that Stiglitz criticises. There, people are basically portrayed as treating time as a dichotomous phenomenon – today and the future — when contemplating making decisions and acting. How much should one consume today and how much in the future? Facing an intertemporal budget constraint of the form

ct + cf/(1+r) = ft + yt + yf/(1+r),

where ct is consumption today, cf is consumption in the future, ft is holdings of financial assets today, yt is labour incomes today, yf is labour incomes in the future, and r is the real interest rate, and having a lifetime utility function of the form

U = u(ct) + au(cf),

where a is the time discounting parameter, the representative agent (consumer) maximizes his utility when

u´(ct) = a(1+r)u´(cf).

This expression – the Euler equation – implies that the representative agent (consumer) is indifferent between consuming one more unit today or instead consuming it tomorrow. Typically using a logarithmic function form – u(c) = log c – which gives u´(c) = 1/c, the Euler equation can be rewritten as

1/ct = a(1+r)(1/cf),

or

cf/ct = a(1+r).

This importantly implies that according to the neoclassical consumption model that changes in the (real) interest rate and the ratio between future and present consumption move in the same direction.

So good, so far. But how about the real world? Is the neoclassical consumption as described in this kind of models in tune with the empirical facts? Hardly — the data and models are as a rule inconsistent!

In the Euler equation, we only have one interest rate, equated to the money market rate as set by the central bank. The crux is that — given almost any specification of the utility function – the two rates are actually often found to be strongly negatively correlated in the empirical literature. The data on returns and aggregate consumption simply are inconsistent with the DSGE models.

Although yours truly shares a lot of Stiglitz’ critique of DSGE modelling — “the standard DSGE model provides a poor basis for policy, and tweaks to it are unlikely to be helpful” —  it has to be said that his more general description of the history and state of modern macroeconomics is less convincing.  Stiglitz notices that some of the greatest deficiencies in DSGE models “relates to the treatment of uncertainty,” but doesn’t really follow up on that core difference between Keynesian ‘genuine uncertainty’ economics and neoclassical ‘stochastic risk’ economics. DSGE models are only the latest outgrow of neoclassical general equilibrium (Arrow-Debreu) economics. And that theory has never, and will never, be a good starting point for constructing good macroeconomic theory and models. When the foundation of the house you build is weak, it will never be somewhere you want to live, no matter how many new — and in Stiglitz’ view better — varieties of ‘micro-foundations’ you add.

8 Comments

  1. I think there is a glimmer of hope for DSGE models.
    .
    To the extent DSGE models take into consideration only intertemporal optimization, they are useless as macroeconomic models.
    .
    There is a burgeoning class of DSGE models which incorporate income effects. To that extent, they might become viable macroeconomic models.
    .
    At the moment I’m not entirely sure how these two aspects work within DSGE models – a matter of further study for me.
    .
    It has to be remembered that Keynes himself said, at full employment, that classical theory (optimization) came into its own.
    .
    There is a very simple way of exposing how optimization and income effects can be married together.

  2. Interestingly, a new DSGE model proves many conclusions I have arrived at independently:
    .
    QUOTE
    .
    The vast majority of the open economy literature is based on net capital flow models. As explained
    by Borio (2016), these modeling frameworks do not separately track physical resource flows and
    monetary financing flows, and therefore implicitly represent physical resources themselves as the
    medium of exchange. This leads directly to statements such as “foreign saving finances the current account”, which treat two distinct concepts, saving and financing, as identical. Saving is a
    goods market concept, it denotes output not consumed. Financing is a money market concept, it
    represents newly created purchasing power in an accepted settlement medium, which in modern
    economies almost exclusively takes the form of commercial bank money. Financing is required
    not only for goods trades but also for asset trades, which are a quantitatively far more important
    component of gross flows. As a result, the magnitudes of net resource flows and stocks and of
    gross financial flows and stocks are disconnected, a phenomenon that has been labelled the “excess
    elasticity” of the financial system by Borio and Disyatat (2011).
    .
    END QUOTE
    .
    Although this model uses horrible assumptions I disagree with, it ends up at the same place I do: that Simon Wren-Lewis’s “gravity model” of trade is wrong because cross-border financial gross flows matter much more that net payment flows.
    .
    I wonder what SWL would say if he bothered to look at this paper? It uses mainstream models to disprove his mainstream theory …

    • Cleaned up quotation:
      .
      The vast majority of the open economy literature is based on net capital flow models. As explained by Borio (2016), these modeling frameworks do not separately track physical resource flows and monetary financing flows, and therefore implicitly represent physical resources themselves as the medium of exchange. This leads directly to statements such as “foreign saving finances the current account”, which treat two distinct concepts, saving and financing, as identical. Saving is a goods market concept, it denotes output not consumed. Financing is a money market concept, it represents newly created purchasing power in an accepted settlement medium, which in modern economies almost exclusively takes the form of commercial bank money. Financing is required not only for goods trades but also for asset trades, which are a quantitatively far more important component of gross flows. As a result, the magnitudes of net resource flows and stocks and of gross financial flows and stocks are disconnected, a phenomenon that has been labelled the “excess elasticity” of the financial system by Borio and Disyatat (2011).
      .
      Link to paper: https://www.bis.org/publ/work890.pdf

  3. Amends Lars I was on a lark … having a bit of fun with being multidisciplinary with computer architectures and history/economics. That said as a case study its quite the eye popper with huge geopolitical, social, and macro ramifications E.g. the kitchen sink.

    >

    I would additionally refer to the tremendous amount of new anthropological data on Mesoamerica and how that effects macro.

  4. I just finished The rise of the rest, by Alice Amsden. In the final chapter there is a marvellous paragraph pertinent to this question, I think:

    “If knowledge is not perfect, then productivity and quality may vary among firms in the same industry in different countries. Consequently, simply allowing the market mechanism to determine the price level (“getting the prices right”) may be insufficient to enable countries to compete internationally in industries in which they may be expected to enjoy a comparative advantage (labor-using industries in the case of labor-abundant countries, raw material-using industries in the case of raw material-abundant countries, and so forth). The price of labor, for example, may have to become negative before a labor-abundant country becomes internationally competitive in the most labor-using industry, holding productivity and quality constant, because the proprietary knowledge-based assets of a higher-wage competitor may earn it lower unit costs – as we saw in the case of the Japanese textile industry vis-à-vis both prewar Indian and Chinese textile industries and the postwar Taiwanese and Korean textile industries.”

    In other words

    “there is not a “Pareto optimal” solution (…) Neither the market nor the institutional approach is on higher moral or theoretical ground. As we saw in “the rest” it may be more growth-enhancing (and faster – about which theory can say nothing) to raise productivity by institutional engineering than to lower costs by cutting wages.”

    Neo-classical theory is bunk. Only experience matters. One can make theories of experience, but it can not be expressed in mathematical terms.

    • @Jan

      .

      All the permiations surrounding Manchester [city] Mfg over 250 years is just an incredible case of floating point multipliers. Links to civil war [bonds (recently offered for sale] over cotton supplies, speed of technical innovation feed back to labour organization, political alliances, investor group dynamics broaching on militant actions, large geopolitical foot print, loss of market share, and now after all that one company a few years ago has taken the top niche spot of high quality cotton product Mfg in the world with raw cotton supplied from California, in a refurbished original textile mill fitted out with the latest high tech processing machinery. That is just the short list.

      .

      PS Lars … son just got an apprenticeship with Volvo CE, sorry chuffed dad.

  5. Reading the linked paper by Stiglitz, I cannot help thinking that the root problem is that economists, including Stiglitz, think they can do policy effectively with only a theory and with no operational model. This would be like trying to fly an airplane with only a theory of aerodynamics, but no model of the particular plane you were trying to control.
    .
    His many devastating criticisms of theory are valid as complaints about the lack of both curiousity and integrity among economists. But, even a good theory would not have the practical utility he wants.
    .
    What is wanted is the knowledge to design and steer the particular machine in particular circumstances. That requires an operational understanding of the institutional order and the ability to discern precisely which state-of-the-world the world is in.
    .
    To build an operational model adequate to policy needs would no doubt require a much better theory. It would also require a methodological awareness that theory cannot substitute for an operational model.

  6. Thus, we also know that individuals do not save a constant fraction of their income, come what may.

    Zero is a constant, and is what most people save


Sorry, the comment form is closed at this time.

Blog at WordPress.com.
Entries and Comments feeds.