What’s wrong with Krugman’s economics?

1 Oct, 2019 at 10:30 | Posted in Economics | 9 Comments

Krugman writes: “So how do you do useful economics? In general, what we really do is combine maximization-and-equilibrium as a first cut with a variety of ad hoc modifications reflecting what seem to be empirical regularities about how both individual behavior and markets depart from this idealized case.”

Alexander  Rosenberg
Duke UniversityBut if you ask the New Classical economists, they’ll say, this is exactly what we do—combine maximizing-and-equilibrium with empirical regularities. And they’d go on to say it’s because Krugman’s Keynesian models don’t do this or don’t do enough of it, they are not “useful” for prediction or explanation …

The trouble is that the macroeconomic evidence can’t tell us when and where maximization-and-equilibrium goes wrong, and there seems no immediate prospect for improving the assumptions of perfect rationality and perfect markets from behavioral economics, neuroeconomics, experimental economics, evolutionary economics, game theory, etc.

But these concessions are all the New Classical economists need to defend themselves against Krugman. After all, he seems to admit there is no alternative to maximization and equilibrium …

One thing that’s missing from Krugman’s treatment of economics is the explicit recognition of what Keynes and before him Frank Knight, emphasized: the persistent presence of enormous uncertainty in the economy …

Alexander Rosenberg

As Rosenberg notes, Krugman works with a very simple modelling dichotomy — either models are complex or they are simple. For years now, self-proclaimed “proud neoclassicist” Paul Krugman has in endless harpings on the same old IS-LM string told us about the splendour of the Hicksian invention — so, of course, to Krugman simpler models are always preferred.

Krugman has argued that ‘Keynesian’ macroeconomics more than anything else “made economics the model-oriented field it has become.” In Krugman’s eyes, Keynes was a “pretty klutzy modeler,” and it was only thanks to Samuelson’s famous 45-degree diagram and Hicks’s IS-LM that things got into place. Although admitting that economists have a tendency to use ”excessive math” and “equate hard math with quality” he still vehemently defends — and always have — the mathematization of economics:

I’ve seen quite a lot of what economics without math and models looks like — and it’s not good.

wrong-tool-by-jerome-awBut if the math-is-the-message-modelers aren’t able to show that the mechanisms or causes that they isolate and handle in their mathematically formalized macromodels are stable in the sense that they do not change when we ‘export’ them to our ‘target systems,’ those mathematical models do only hold under ceteris paribus conditions and are consequently of limited value to our understandings, explanations and predictions of real economic systems.

For years now, Krugman has criticized mainstream economics for using too much (bad) mathematics and axiomatics in their model-building endeavours. But when it comes to defending his own position on various issues he usually himself ultimately falls back on the same kind of models. In his End This Depression Now — just to take one example — Paul Krugman maintains that although he doesn’t buy “the assumptions about rationality and markets that are embodied in many modern theoretical models, my own included,” he still find them useful “as a way of thinking through some issues carefully.”

When it comes to methodology and assumptions, Krugman obviously has a lot in common with the kind of model-building he otherwise criticizes.

If macroeconomic models — no matter of what ilk — make assumptions, and we know that real people and markets cannot be expected to obey these assumptions, the warrants for supposing that conclusions or hypotheses of causally relevant mechanisms or regularities can be bridged, are obviously non-justifiable.

So let me — respectfully — summarize: A gadget is just a gadget — and brilliantly silly simple models — IS-LM included — do not help us working with the fundamental issues of modern economies any more than brilliantly silly complicated models — calibrated DSGE and RBC models included. And as Rosenberg rightly notices:

When he accepts maximizing and equilibrium as the (only?) way useful economics is done Krugman makes a concession so great it threatens to undercut the rest of his arguments against New Classical economics.

9 Comments

  1. “the warrants for supposing that conclusions or hypotheses of causally relevant mechanisms or regularities can be bridged”
    .
    The warrants are the Profit and Loss books of traders, and the models producing the trades are in research documents from JP Morgan, Bank of America, Citi Research, Goldman Sachs research, and the like.

  2. Lars,
    .
    As interesting as it is reading your diatribes (which I mostly agree with) against mainstream economics isn’t it about time you explain, in detail, with what mainstream economics should be replaced?

    • Henry, just as Rosenberg I am a science theoretician and economic methodologist criticizing the way (some) economists do economics. When a literary critic criticize a novelist’s novel, telling him to write a novel himself can’t be the right thing to ask for …

      • Lars,
        .
        I don’t think that’s a very strong argument at all and the analogy is inappropriate. A novel is unique and idiosyncratic and is based on a totally constructed and imagined situation meant for entertainment. An economic theory is meant to be all encompassing and applicable to the real world (hopefully) and have practical application in policy. OK, the mainstream may not pass all those tests with flying colours but perhaps it is a beginning or a basis for ongoing work.
        .
        For your argument to have weight I think you should provide an alternative or at least the semblance of an alternative, a direction in which to travel.
        .
        If you can’t think of something better then maybe there is no better way than the mainstream (not that I believe this at all) and your criticism is in vain and you may as well make the best of the mainstream.

        • “A novel is unique and idiosyncratic and is based on a totally constructed and imagined situation meant for entertainment.”

          I’m not sure. I think there is a lot more depth and truth, and even less fiction, in Orwell’s 1984 or Dickens’ Great Expectations than in Krugman’s gadgets or sticky price rational expectations optimisation models. And an even better forecasting record.

          Prescient stuff.

          Words are more powerful than models.

    • Henry, my answer to that is that it shouldn’t be replaced with anything – but it should have a bit of everything. It can’t be closed discipline. It must be a multidisciplinary one that’s constantly changing. It’s a social science. Understanding how a financial crisis like 2008 happens is like understanding how WWI happened. Psychologists, historians, sociologists, country experts, can all have something to say. But there are unlikely to be universal laws that will apply everywhere at all times. For example in international relations, there are theories of how conflict happens. To understand how a particular conflict happened, however, you have to start from the ground up. Every time. Like a good lawyer, or a good doctor, or a good psychologist, a good economist will just have a good knowledge built up from numerous case studies. From that he will be able to make the best judgement possible regarding the policy response.

      An undergraduate international relations theory textbook used in the UK, for example, for me would be a good model of an undergraduate economics textbook. Take Burchill Theory of International Relations (Palgrave). In there you have Marxian, Neo-liberal and other major contrasting theories. Within the discussion the major methodological and other issues are brought into attention (eg. when is formalism appropriate). Undergraduates are taught to understand the meanings of things like ontology and epistemology.

      • Or more particularly, neo-Marxian vs rational choice based approaches. Classical liberalism and neo-liberalism fall into the latter category in political science, so clearly does mainstream (neo-classical) economics (for reasons people need to understand).

        It is important we understand how this means by which economists view the world became so dominant. People argue that economists disagree. Actually they don’t when it comes to methodology.

        People also need to understand that it is only one way of looking at the world – and most likely, a very flawed one. That makes questions about why it is so dominant even more pertinent.

  3. You’re not going to read anything interesting, informed or helpful by Krugman. The liquidity trap article on Japan is a good example. There is an important story here: how a system designed to achieve rapid recovery and growth after WWII was deregulated from the 1970s and created an asset price bubble and crash in the 80s and 90s, of which zero interest rates are a symptom. To understand why there are low interest rates you need to read the Japanese language literature. There is nothing in Krugman’s ‘seminal’ article that tells us really what happened in capitalism, and Japanese capitalism in particular, that created that situation. The response was also informed by Japanese macro-economic practice that has a long tradition – in this sense it was not as ‘unconventional’ as many people may think.

  4. I have no respect for Krugman, whatsoever, and the more I study economics the more I think it is truly a danger to humanity.


Sorry, the comment form is closed at this time.

Blog at WordPress.com.
Entries and Comments feeds.