Greg Mankiw’s libertarian quasi philosophy

10 Feb, 2015 at 11:25 | Posted in Economics | 6 Comments

libertarianism-anarchy-for-rich-peopleAs yours truly has commented on earlier, walked-out Harvard economist and George Bush advisor Greg Mankiw is having problems with explaining the rising inequality we have seen for the last 30 years in both the US and elsewhere in Western societies, that says it . He writes:

Even if the income gains are in the top 1 percent, why does that imply that the right story is not about education?

I then realized that Paul is making an implicit assumption–that the return to education is deterministic. If indeed a year of schooling guaranteed you precisely a 10 percent increase in earnings, then there is no way increasing education by a few years could move you from the middle class to the top 1 percent.

But it may be better to think of the return to education as stochastic. Education not only increases the average income a person will earn, but it also changes the entire distribution of possible life outcomes. It does not guarantee that a person will end up in the top 1 percent, but it increases the likelihood. I have not seen any data on this, but I am willing to bet that the top 1 percent are more educated than the average American; while their education did not ensure their economic success, it played a role.

This is, of course, nothing but evasion, trying to explain away a very disturbing structural shift that has taken place in our societies. And change that has very little to do with stochastic returns to education. Those were in place also 30 or 40 years ago. At that time they meant that perhaps a CEO earned 10-12 times what “ordinary” people earns. Today it means that they perhaps earn 100-200 times what “ordinary” people earns. A question of education? No way! It is a question of greed and a lost sense of a common project of building a sustainable society. A result of stochastic returns to education? No, this has to do with income and wealth increasingly being concentrated in the hands of a very small and privileged elite.

Mankiw has stubbornly refused to nudge on his libertarian stance on this issue. And obviously yours truly is not the only economist who is critical:

I have let Greg Mankiw’s latest piece for the New York Times simmer in my brain for a few days, and now I have to let some of the noxious vapors escape.

Here’s what he says. Most economic choices are complex, with positive and negative effects on many parties. The utilitarian calculus, the greatest good for the greatest number, doesn’t work, because it means helping some people by hurting others. Unless there is a clear case of market failure—externalities—it is best to defer to the voluntary choices made by individuals in a free market.
libertarian at a dinner party

What makes it difficult to respond is the multitude of errors and omissions in the Mankiw formulation. It’s hard to know where to begin, so let me just make a list. All of these are interconnected, of course, so the whole list is more than the sum of its elements.

1. Externalities are not the only market failure! It’s scary that one of the planet’s most widely read undergraduate textbook authors could say this. For the record, you’ve also got imperfect competition, public goods and asymmetric information, and together they apply to a lot of economic terrain.

2. A different issue, not yet classified under market failure, is multiplicity of equilibrium. I’ve written a lot on this in the past and won’t repeat myself here, but interaction effects between economic agents, as well as the goods and services they produce, routinely make possible potential returns to collective action. To not see this is to not see the “social” in social science.

3. It is true that market transactions, if participants are self-interested and rational, filter out possible actions that make some better off at the expense of others. But surely to rule out all social change that is not voluntarily accepted on all sides is to commit to an extreme conservatism. The world we live in is the product of the past, with all the irrationalities and inequalities that have been transmitted to us by history. Maybe, just maybe, we might want to rectify some of them, even if history’s beneficiaries are against it.

4. Embedded in Mankiw’s quasi-libertarianism is a profound distrust of democracy. No one, he says, can reasonably weigh the competing claims of the winners and losers from a policy proposal. Well, that’s what democracy is supposed to do. In theory, we discuss it. We ask people to not simply assert their interests but give reasons why society should defer to them, and then we assess these reasons. Obviously, actually existing democracy falls far short of the ideal, but its performance is not completely worthless, and there is untapped potential even in existing institutions to do this job a lot better. It isn’t hard to find examples from modern history where democracies have risen to the occasion and brought about social change that, in hindsight, most of us now endorse. I sentence Mankiw to 40 hours of mandatory service to his own brain, in the form of reading John Dewey on democratic theory. He can get started here.

I can see the value in giving people plenty of scope to make voluntarily arrangements with one another. There is real freedom involved, and it’s important that there be lots of opportunities for individuals to take initiative as they see fit. But this is one value among several, and its weight varies from one policy context to the next. Knee-jerk libertarianism is simply lazy philosophy.

Peter Dorman

6 Comments

  1. Speaking as a libertarian myself (but not a “knee-jerk” one), I think this is spot on.

    1 is inexcusable, but the other 3 seem pretty typical stances for a lot of economists.

    Regarding 2, I think economists are too quick to assume equilibria and assume lack of equilibria must mean a bad model. Indeed, it seems to me that a lot of macroeconomic models take the social out of the social science via another means: by assuming agent preferences and expectations are independently determined. The whole rational/adaptive expectations debate completely misses out that people’s expectations of the future are socially influenced, and that both optimism and pessimism are contagious.

    In regards to 3, I’ve always been a bit mystified at why Pareto efficiency is such a big deal. I was heartened to see such a stinging critique of it here. As for 4, that’s pretty much the Public Choice stance in a nutshell. Is that the only school of economic thought that focuses at the political process? It’s the only one I know about, which seems to be a shame.

    I’ve often thought that liberal economists are the ones who see market failure everywhere because they want more government, while conservative economists are those who see government failure everywhere because they want more markets — meaning that there are too few actually trying to improve the actual workings of the political economy (never mind creating models that accurately forecast).

  2. Economists’ ultimate goal is to say things to gain publicity. More people are wealthy today than they were 100 years ago because of education. But education is not enough. It requires IQ and hard work. Most people neither have the IQ nor the will to work hard. They prefer to be in civil service jobs.

    I would like truly ours to answer why the lotto jackpot is not distributed uniformly among winners and usually the bulk of the money goes to the top winner. Is this a blunt case of discrimination or there is a good reason for that? Why in a lottery with 6 numbers, the one that picks the six correctly (by chance) wins millions but the one that picks 4 wins a few euros or dollars only. It appears that the difference from 4 to 6 is huge, give probability theory. So is the difference between being a secretary and a CEO. Secretary makes a few euros and the CEO millions. Do not look for reasons as to why the secretary stayed secretary and the CEO became CEO. It is all randomness. The secretary could be the CEO and vice versa. The fact is the difference, like in the lottery. Denying the difference is a denial of reality and lack of pragmatism. Of course, there is a parallel universe in which a CEO makes 100,000 and the secretary 50,000 but in that universe maybe dogs have wings and people have two heads.

    I invite you read my post on inequality, a pragmatic approach.

    http://www.digitalcosmology.com/Blog/2013/06/23/the-top-1-controversy-and-false-dilemma/

    • Fairly massive assumptions about humanity you do throughout the argument, there.

    • A) “More people are wealthy (sic) today than they were 100 years ago because of education.”

      B) “Do not look for reasons why the secretary stayed secretary and the CEO became CEO.”

      C) “It’s all randomness.”

      In your comment A) history matters, in your comment B) history doesn’t matter. So which is it?

      If your comment C) is correct than why don’t we see CEOs distributed proportionately across races, ethnicities, and gender?

  3. It boils down to asymmetric power in a class-based society, since the ruling elite determine the legal and other institutional arrangement that underlie markets. The chief flaw of conventional economics is failure to look at political science and sociology, which explain the issues clearly and show the reasons for conventional economics being a waste of time in that the models described ideal systems that don’t actually exist and cannot actually exist in a modern society. Of course, heterodox economists do too because they get out while conventional economists seldom bother to look out the window.

    This is revealed by the basic neoliberal and Libertarian utopian premise that everything would be fine if there were no government intrusion in markets. This is really the assertion that everything would be fine if there were no institutional arrangements at all other than a general agreement not to aggress. Remarkable that they cannot see that this is utopian idealism that makes no practical sense in the contemporary world.

    The basic difference between neoliberalism and Libertarianism is that Libertarianism is actually utopian, where as neoliberalism is based on the ruling elite controlling the process and pretending “freedom and democracy,” when the reality is oligarchic plutonomy, as the Citigroup plutonomy report acknowledged.

    Until conventional economics takes cognizance of poli sci and sociology, not to mention complexity, conventional economists will have their heads either in the clouds or buried in the sand on which they stand. There is no foundation there in the real.

    The bottom line is power and who holds it. Economically, power enables the extraction of economic rents that are the basis of wealth and influence. Power is class-based. Of course, flaks for the ruling class will never admit this and demonize it as “Marxism” and “communism.” Other conventional economists go along to get along even though they must realize the truth of the matter unless they are incredibly stupid.

  4. It is the usual nonsense, trying to explain structural social phenomenon with personal properties. What he is saying is that the rich should be rich, because they are better and have better personal properties.

    Education as a means for the people to gain ground on the inequality is a blatant lie. His own theories of wages contradict this lie. “Natural unemployment” is not merely a system wide phenomenon, every business that rely on a certain skill for its existence will come in crisis when this skill is rare and wages rise rapidly. Education leads to a reserve workforce pushing wages down in different fields. So he is lying and he knows it.

    Shameful!


Sorry, the comment form is closed at this time.

Blog at WordPress.com.
Entries and Comments feeds.